JohnConover_medium.jpg 
john@email.johncon.com
http://www.johncon.com/john/

World Historical Economics


Home | John | Connie | Publications | Software | Correspondence | NtropiX | NdustriX | NformatiX | NdeX | Thanks



home.jpg
john.jpg
connie.jpg
publications.jpg
software.jpg
correspondence.jpg
ntropix.jpg
ndustrix.jpg
nformatix.jpg
ndex.jpg
thanks.jpg

World Gross Domestic Product

The GDP metric is in 1990 Nominal International Dollars, and is in real dollars, relative to the value of the US dollar in 1990.


world.gdp1.jpg

Figure I

Figure I is a plot of the World GDP, 1,000,000BCE through 2,000CE, in 1990 International Dollars. The World GDP is shown only since the late stone age, about -5,000BCE. Note the hockey stick of the exponential increase of the World GDP.


world.gdp2.jpg

Figure II

Figure II is the same plot of the World GDP, 1,000,000BCE through 2,000CE, in 1990 International Dollars. The World GDP is shown only since the late stone age, about -5,000BCE, with the ordinate expanded for clarity.


world.gdp3.jpg

Figure III

Figure III is the same plot of the World GDP, 1,000,000BCE through 2,000CE, in 1990 International Dollars. The World GDP shown includes only the modern economy, about the Sixteenth Century CE.


World Population


world.population1.jpg

Figure IV

Figure IV is a plot of the World Population, 10,000BCE through 2,010CE. The World Population is showen only since the late stone age, about -5,000BCE. Note the concatenation of UN data past 1950.


world.population2.jpg

Figure V

Figure V is the same plot of the World Population, 10,000BCE through 2,010CE. The World Population shown is only up to the the modern economy, about the Sixteenth Century CE.


world.population3.jpg

Figure VI

Figure VI is the same plot of the World Population, 10,000BCE through 2,010CE. The World Population shown includes only the modern economy, from about the Sixteenth Century CE.


World Gross Domestic Product per Capita

Note that this is an analysis of the World GDP per capita, (using the mean GDP per capita, as opposed to the median GDP per capita, which, alas, is not available, and is the World GDP divided by the World Population.)


world.gdp.capita1.jpg

Figure VII

Figure VII is a plot produced by dividing the World GDP by the World Population, and is the mean GDP per capita, 10,000BCE through 2,000CE. Clearly, the standard of living didn't change from subsistence levels, (the so called Malthusian stagnation, proposed by Thomas Robert Malthus, 1766-1834,) until the advent of the modern economy, about the Sixteenth Century CE.


world.gdp.capita2.jpg

Figure VIII

Figure VIII is the same plot produced by dividing the World GDP by the World Population, and is the mean GDP per capita, 10,000BCE through 2,000CE, but values past the Sixteenth Century, the beginning of the modern economy, have been truncated. Clearly, the standard of living didn't change from subsistence levels until the advent of the modern economy.


world.gdp.capita3.jpg

Figure IX

Figure IX is the same plot produced by dividing the World GDP by the World Population, and is the mean GDP per capita, 10,000BCE through 2,000CE, but values past the Sixteenth Century, the beginning of the modern economy, have been truncated. Clearly, the standard of living didn't change from subsistence levels until the advent of the modern economy. Temperature observations from holocene.climate.txt were added, and will be persued further on in the study.


world.gdp.capita4.jpg

Figure X

Figure X is the same plot produced by dividing the World GDP by the World Population, and is the mean GDP per capita, 10,000BCE through 2,000CE, but only values past the Sixteenth Century, the beginning of the modern economy, are shown. Clearly, the standard of living started to increase, rapidly, from many millennia of stagnation at subsistence levels, with the advent of the modern economy.


world.gdp.capita.increments1.jpg

Figure XI

Figure XI is the annual fractional increments of the world GDP per capita, (i.e., dividing the World GDP by the World Population, and is the mean GDP per capita, 10,000BCE through 2,000CE, annualized, to provide the increase in the standard of living per year.) The beginning of the modern economy, is clearly evident.


world.gdp.capita.increments2.jpg

Figure XII

Figure XII is the annual fractional increments of the world GDP per capita, (i.e., dividing the World GDP by the World Population, and is the mean GDP per capita, 10,000BCE through 2,000CE, annualized, to provide the increase in the standard of living per year,) but only values past the Sixteenth Century, the beginning of the modern economy, are shown.


world.temperature1.jpg

Figure XIII

Figure XIII is a plot of the World's surface temperature, 2,500BCE through 2,000CE.


As a side bar, the weather is a non-linear dynamical system, (often called chaotic,) and, as a first order approximation, (e.g., mathematical expediency,) is analyzed as a geometric Brownian motion process using methodologies from econophysics:



    tsmath -t -l temperature.txt | tsderivative -t | tsavg -p
    0.000202
    tsmath -t -l temperature.txt | tsderivative -t | tsrms -p
    0.013498
              

And calculating the chances of an increase in temperature in any century out of the 45 centuries:



    avg=0.000202
    rms=0.013498
    P(avg,rms)
            0.50748259001333530893 .................................(B-1.24)

              

Or, working with the marginal increments:



    tsfraction -t temperature.txt | tsavg -p
    0.000293
    tsfraction -t temperature.txt | tsrms -p
    0.013471

              

And calculating the chances of an increase in temperature in any century out of the 45 centuries:



    avg=0.000293
    rms=0.013471
    P(avg,rms)
            0.51087521342142379927 .................................(B-1.24)

              

Meaning there is about a 51% chance that the next century will be warmer than the current century, for any century out of the last 45 centuries, (with an rms standard error of about 15%, meaning the value of avg is presumptive.)

The optimal wager on that would be, (via the Kelly Criterion):



    (2 * P ) - 1 = 2 * 0.51 - 1 = 0.02 .............................(B-1.18)

              

or about 2% of capital, per century-based on the presumptive value of avg. The multiplicity increase in temperature, per century, G would be:



    G = (1 + rms)^P * (1 - rms)^(1 - P) = 1.00020229603023145739 ...(B-1.20)

              

Or, over the 45 centuries, 57 * 1.00020229603023145739^45 or about a half degree C.

Completing the analysis, (geometric Brownian Motion fractals have exponential characteristics, and so far the analysis has been from the inside out,) of the outside in, (via exponential LSQ):



    tslsq -e -p temperature.txt
    e^(4.044849 + -0.000006t)

              

And calculating:



    exp(4.044849)
            57.10256289611706131889

    exp(-0.000006)
            0.999994000017999964

              

which indicates a very small value for the avg, (as expected; it is actually a very small negative value, about 6e-6, in the exponential LSQ analysis, but still well within the standard error.)

The indications are that, as a first order approximation, the world temperature for the last 45 centuries can be represented as a geometric Brownian Motion fractal, and has the implication that it is not ergodic, (in the sense that the growth rate of the ensemble average of the disturbances in temperature does not equal the time average growth rate.) The stability of the temperature over the last 45 centuries could be attributed to negative feedback mechanisms, and zero of the geometric Brownian Motion fractal possibly absolute zero-which would make sense.


Note that photo synthesis is a chemical process. The Arrhenius Equation determines the reaction rate of a chemical process as a function of temperature, so agricultural production should be coherent with temperature. (Of course, the climate is a complex system, and depends on many variables-however, temperature is among the most significant.)


world.temperature2.jpg

Figure XIV

Figure XIV is a plot of the Arrhenius reaction rate, and, the mean World GDP per capita, both LSQ normalized to unity over the interval of 2,500BCE to 2,000CE.

It appears that there is a correlation, but the temperature data seems to be shifted a couple of centuries, (which is not uncommon due to data processing/smoothing at the millennia level.) In a private correspondence with Randy Mann, (Long Range Weather), it is possible the shift is a data processing artifact.


world.temperature2-300.jpg

Figure XV

Figure XV is a plot of the Arrhenius reaction rate, and, the mean World GDP per capita, both LSQ normalized to unity over the interval of 2,500BCE to 2,000CE, with the temperature shifted 3 centuries.

It does appear that throughout the history of civilization, GDP was dominated by agricultural production, (at least until the advent of the modern economy,) placing humanity at the whim of the weather.


world.gdp.capita.deviation.jpg

Figure XVI

Figure XVI is a plot of the deviation from the median of the arithmetic fractional Brownian motion equivalent of mean World GDP per capita, from the stone age, about -5000BCE, through 2000CE. (For details, see: Quantitative Analysis of Non-Linear High Entropy Economic Systems II.) This methodology is useful for studying bubbles in geometric Brownian motion fractal time series.


world.gdp.capita.deviation1.jpg

Figure XVII

Figure XVII is a plot of the deviation from the median of the arithmetic fractional Brownian motion equivalent of mean World GDP per capita, from the stone age, about -5000BCE, through 2000CE. (For details, see: Quantitative Analysis of Non-Linear High Entropy Economic Systems II.) There are several techniques for deriving the arithmetic fractional Brownian motion equivalent from the geometric fractal, and all produce equivalent results, within reason, (if the time series really is a geometric fractional Brownian motion process.) Most of the techniques involve taking the logarithm of the time series, (as opposed to working with the marginal increments.)

The World GDP data is not a pure time series, (the early data is spotty,) but this verifies that techniques involving the logarithm are, at least reasonably so, valid.


world.gdp.capita.log1.jpg

Figure XVIII

Figure XVIII is a log-log plot of the mean World GDP per capita, -5,000BCE, the late stone age, through 2,000CE. Included variables are the World GDP, the World population, and the US nominal GDP since 1790, (converted to 1990 International Dollars.)


world.gdp.capita.log2.jpg

Figure XVIV

Figure XVIV is the same log-log plot of the mean World GDP per capita, -5,000BCE, the late stone age, through 2,000CE, but showing only the late 1700s through 2,000CE. Included variables are the World GDP, the World population, and the US nominal GDP since 1790, (converted to 1990 International Dollars.) Notice the concatenation of data for the World population with UN data past 1950.

Of interest is the comparison of the mean GDP per capita of the US and the mean GDP per capita of the world, prior to about 1950, i.e., post WWII. Of further interest is the inflection in the US GDP per capita about 1974.


world.gdp.capita.log3.jpg

Figure XX

Figure XX is the same log-log plot of the mean World GDP per capita, -5,000BCE, the late stone age, through 2,000CE. Included variables are the World GDP, the World population, and the US nominal GDP since 1790, (converted to 1990 International Dollars.) Additionally, historical comments of the era are added, for convenience, and, LSQ approximations to the curves.


world.gdp.capita.log4.jpg

Figure XXI

Figure XXI is the same log-log plot of the mean World GDP per capita, -5,000BCE, the late stone age, through 2,000CE. The plot is centered around the start of the modern economy. Included variables are the World GDP, the World population, and the US nominal GDP since 1790, (converted to 1990 International Dollars.) Additionally, historical comments of the era are added, for convenience, and, LSQ approximations to the curves.

It would appear that from, at least, -5,000BCE, the late stone age, to the early 1600s CE, the mean World GDP per capita remained constant, at about subsistence levels. In the early 1600s, (depending on who's calibrated eye is telling the story,) the modern economy began, and the GDP per capita, i.e., the standard of living, started increasing at an exponential rate. This would be coincident with the Scientific Revolution.


world.gdp.capita.log5.jpg

Figure XXII is the same log-log plot of the mean World GDP per capita, -5,000BCE, the late stone age, through 2,000CE. The plot is centered later, around the late 1800s, well into the advent of the modern economy. Included variables are the World GDP, the World population, and the US nominal GDP since 1790, (converted to 1990 International Dollars.) Additionally, historical comments of the era are added, for convenience, and, LSQ approximations to the curves.

Up to this point in the study of the mean World GDP per capita, the assumption is that the GDP system was a geometric fractional Brownian motion process, which is often used, (at least as an approximation,) for analyzing the data from complex systems. Numerically, there are but small differences between a geometric fractional Brownian motion process, and a non-linear dynamical system, (usually a relatively small negative parameter in the marginal increments of the data.) Proceeding on that assumption, the simplest chaotic system is the Logistic Function, (also called the discreet time parabolic function in Europe,) which has a single Strange Attractor. In addition to initially exhibiting exponential characteristics, the Logistic Function is S shaped, over time.


world.gdp.capita.lsq1.jpg

Figure XXIII

Figure XXIII is a log-log plot of the mean World GDP per capita, -5,000BCE through 2,000CE, and several exponential and logistic LSQ approximations to the data, centered around the advent of the modern economy. The LSQ approximations were iterated at approximately century intervals for best fit candidates, and extrapolated to 2,200CE.


world.gdp.capita.lsq2.jpg

Figure XXIV is the same log-log plot of the mean World GDP per capita, -5,000BCE through 2,000CE, and two best exponential LSQ approximation candidates, and, the two best logistic LSQ approximation candidates, centered around the advent of the modern economy. The LSQ approximations were extrapolated to 2,200CE.

The logistic function analysis will be pursued from here on.


world.gdp.capita.increments.jpg

Figure XXV

Figure XXV is a plot of the annual fractional increments, (i.e., marginal increments,) of the mean World GDP per capita, -5,000BCE through 2,000CE, and the fractional increments of the best logistic LSQ approximation candidate, centered around 2,000CE. The analysis was done on half century data, and extrapolated to 2,400CE.


world.gdp.capita.lsq-a1.jpg

Figure XXVI

Figure XXVI is a log-log plot of the mean World GDP per capita, -5,000BCE through 2,000CE, and several logistic LSQ approximations to the data, centered around the advent of the modern economy. The LSQ approximations were iterated as shown for best fit candidates, and extrapolated to 2,200CE. The analysis was done on half century data.


world.gdp.capita.lsq-a2.jpg

Figure XXVII

Figure XXVII is the same log-log plot of the mean World GDP per capita, -5,000BCE through 2,000CE, and the four best LSQ approximations to the data, centered around the advent of the modern economy, and extrapolated to 2,200CE.

world.gdp.capita.increments-a.jpg

Figure XXVIII

Figure XXVIII is a plot of the fractional increments, (i.e., marginal increments,) of the mean World GDP per capita, -5,000BCE through 2,000CE, and the fractional increments of the four best LSQ approximations to the data, centered around 2,000CE, and extrapolated to 2,400CE.

Note that this establishes a plausibility that the mean World GDP per capita is a non-linear dynamical system process, which is of little value. The probability that it is is more useful.


del-del-world.gdp.capita.jpg

Figure XXIV

Figure XXIV is a plot of the change in the change of the mean World GDP per capita, -5,000BCE through 2,000CE, based on century data.



Archive

The data presented here can be reconstructed, in its entirety, from the historical.economics.tar.gz tape archive file, which contains all data and references, thereto. The source code to all programs used in the analysis is available from the NtropiX site, tsinvest.tar.gz, and, the NdustrixX site, fractal.tar.gz, tape archive files. All use the "standard" Unix development systems of rcs(1) and make(1) to facilitate replication.

It should be noted that many of the data set sizes are pitifully small-some as few as two hundred data points, (a standard error of about 7% of the standard deviation,) and conclusions can only be regarded as circumstantial.


License

The information contained herein is private and confidential and dissemination is strictly forbidden, except under the provisions of contractual license.

THE AUTHOR PROVIDES NO WARRANTIES WHATSOEVER, EXPRESSED OR IMPLIED, INCLUDING WARRANTIES OF MERCHANTABILITY, TITLE, OR FITNESS FOR ANY PARTICULAR PURPOSE. THE AUTHOR DOES NOT WARRANT THAT USE OF THIS INFORMATION DOES NOT INFRINGE THE INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS OF ANY THIRD PARTY IN ANY COUNTRY.

So there.

Copyright © 1992-2016, John Conover, All Rights Reserved.

Comments, questions, and problem reports should be addressed to:

john@email.johncon.com

http://www.johncon.com/john/
http://www.johncon.com/ntropix/
http://www.johncon.com/ndustrix/
http://www.johncon.com/nformatix/
http://www.johncon.com/ndex/



Home | John | Connie | Publications | Software | Correspondence | NtropiX | NdustriX | NformatiX | NdeX | Thanks


Copyright © 1992-2016 John Conover, john@email.johncon.com. All Rights Reserved.
Last modified: Sat Feb 18 11:45:25 PST 2017 $Id: world.historical.economics.html,v 1.0 2017/02/18 19:46:12 conover Exp $
Valid HTML 4.0!